S&S LOGO


EDITORIAL PERSPECTIVES (continued)

Finally, the third group of vendors, who may be part-time or full-time, completes the spectrum by representing its high end. These are the purveyors of quality goods: fine art, vintage furniture, real (non-costume) jewelry, often from different countries or with genuine antique value. These vendors must be expert in their fields, must know their merchandise, and their customers, They work very hard acquiring goods, must be skilled at determining optimal rotations of stock, and must be sensitive to changing tastes and styles. Among the more successful vendors in this class, significant incomes can be made, although markups are often not as large as on the cheaper ranges of goods. From a socioeconomic standpoint, the high-end flea-market vendors soak up a considerable amount of discretionary income from the more affluent customers. The growth of this category, as well as of its opposite number in the first category, together reflect, and symbolize, the increasing polarization of income and wealth in recent decades.

Does any of this answer the "flea markets and socialism" question? The beginning of an answer may be found by considering the underlying social processes represented by vendor categories 1 and 3. First, a reserve of casual labor both weakens employed labor, contributing to increasing exploitation and polarization, and provides a safety valve defusing the potential political crisis associated with deepening unemployment and underemployment. (The unemployed, in effect, have a place to go — flea markets.) Second, the high end within flea markets, along with the high end of the formal retail sector, is a partial return to the visible flaunting of wealth that characterized earlier epochs in U. S. capitalist history. Power consumption motivates the elites and middle strata, maintaining ideological control; it also sends symbols of the unbreakable permanence of the existing social order to the lower levels of the class structure.

Socialism has no use for a reserve army of un- and underemployed workers. This negative incentive to submit to being exploited will have been replaced long since by the positive incentive of individual and collective self-development. Indeed, the basic premise of a materialist socialism is that this transition from lower to higher forms of incentive and consciousness is not only desirable; it is essential for the continued development of the productive forces, with due concern for the ecological constraint. A maturing socialist society, then, will not ask any of its members to accept the rigors of casual salesmanship — indeed, would not have the mechanisms in place to make such a "request."

Similarly, socialism rejects — progressively sloughs off — all distorting associations of consumption with status and power. As the core living standard rises, people gradually become accustomed to appreciating consumption for intrinsic reasons and not for invidious ones. The prospect of individually owning valuable collectibles — as opposed, for example, to participating in acquiring them as part of groups of people for community use and appreciation (in museums, public spaces, schools, etc.) — will be increasingly less attractive. Absent also the perverse income distribution characteristic of capitalist societies, the basis for the high-end flea-market sector will atrophy.

There remains the middle range, and I like to imagine that a socialism born of our deepest cultural traditions will be able to provide the infrastructures for people to come together, on weekends or whenever, to swap those wonderful memorabilia and artefacts of times past, and to help overcome the remnants of standardization and "mallification" — to find things that enrich our consumption, and our living spaces, with singularity and fine detail and a sense of history, and of time. Perhaps with basic human needs irreversibly taken care of, and with acquisition-for-acquisition's-sake becoming increasingly foreign to the popular culture, we will still come together in flea markets — not so much as buyers and sellers but as sharers and preservers of our rich goods culture, and history. Thus — the socialist flea market. Hunger, and greed, and rivalry, all wither away. Postage stamp collections, Irish tin whistles, glorious old-fashioned woolen scarves, and hand-blown glass remain forever.

--------------<>-----------------

IN THIS ISSUE

The present period of global polarization and shift in the world balance of forces in favor of capital may be understood, at least partially, as a crisis of capitalist expanded reproduction: a manifestation of capitalism's inability to carry forward its historic role of transforming the world in its own image. The vacuum created by the loss of postcapitalist state power in large parts of the world, is being filled by a resurgent religious fundamentalism, most notably in the Islamic countries of the Middle East, Central and South Asia. A parallel development is the re-emergence of Christian fundamentalism, in a peculiar right-wing form, in the United States. This attack against secularism is also a sign of capitalist weakness, a retreat from the confident cosmopolitanism and univeralism of the early bourgeoisie, as well as an element in the retreat of working-class cultural and political influence from the mid–20th century on. If we are to grasp these phenomena seriously, they must be placed within the frame of a Marxist understanding of religion in general, and for this a quite reasonable starting point would be the work of Marx and Engels and subsequent generations of Marxists on the subject.

The study by Alexander Saxton, "Marxism, Labor and the Failed Critique of Religion," begins this long-overdue inquiry. Saxton collects the scattered references to religion in the early writings, notes Marx's claim that the criticism of religion is the premise of all criticism, and traces the subsequent failure of either the founding or later generations to carry this forward on a systematic level. One conclusion is that, in the interest of working-class political unity, Marxists have often avoided any sort of confrontation with religious belief. The spirit of Christian-Marxist dialog, for example, has often been one of seeking common ground while postponing full examination of the foundations of both religious and secular belief systems. While Saxton does not outline the analysis whose absence he decries, the idea is planted that, perhaps ironically, a more frank and direct confrontation with religious philosophy from a materialist and secular standpoint may be needed, if genuine unity-in-action between secular left forces and the progressive elements and potentials within the religious communities is to be forged.

One early Marxist contribution to the study of religion came from the well-known German Social Democrat, Karl Kautsky; his Foundations of Christianity was first published in 1908. Kautsky was famously subjected to the formidable polemical attention of V. I. Lenin, and his image today is dominated by imputations of mechanistic, determinist, and crudely evolutionist ideas. It is time, says author Paul Blackledge ("Karl Kautsky and Marxist Historiography") to repudiate this image, and to go back to Kautsky's work, on the early Church but also on the United States and Russian social formations, for the genuine insights it contains. This is partly a matter of distinguishing carefully between the earlier and later work, and not rejecting the former in toto because of deficiencies in the latter. There is also a need to separate Kautsky's positions — as, for instance, on the revolutionary potential of the U. S. working class — from the manner of their expression, which does, Blackledge acknowledges, use formulations that come down to us today as fatalistic or abstractly universal.

We are always pleased to learn that work presented in S&S is not only being read, but is considered sufficiently outrageous to provoke the reader to action! (Readers of the current issue, take note!) For some reason, we have experienced a convergence of several debates on topics in Marxist economic theory, which we have brought together as a Symposium, "Debate in Political Economy." (I wish we could claim to have planned it this way.) Debate always sparks interest, and interest is the root of knowledge acquisition. I will not try to summarize the contents of these varied interventions, concerning absolute rent, homo economicus, the theory of value, and the theory of accumulation & crisis, except to observe that continuing controversy in these areas moves us greatly forward in the development of a political economy tradition that can have a forceful presence in current political discussion and give that discussion more secure foundations. We hope that this spirit of comradely exchange of views will spill over into many other areas of investigation in our pages.

Steve Ellner's Communication, "The Defensive Strategy of the Left in Latin America," completes a round of discussion provoked by his earlier article in S&S (Spring 2004), which led to the Symposium among three noted personalities on the Latin American left, Jorge Castañeda, Marta Harnecker and James Petras (April 2005). Present-day promising political developments aside, the Latin American experience is a unique and fertile testing ground for the ever-vital strategic needs of the worldwide left, and we hope potential contributors will continue to share their insights with us.

Finally, we are pleased to present Bettina Aptheker's review-essay on the remarkable autobiography, Fireweed, by Gerda Lerner. Lerner's extraordinary political life began in Austria in the 1930s in the emerging resistance to the Anschluss, continued in the United States in the political ambit of the Communist Party, and flowered subsequently in her work as a pioneer women's historian and feminist. The later period, exemplified by Lerner's writings in the 1990s, is better known, but Fireweed now tells the earlier part of the story, with unusual honesty and both political and psychological insight. Readers should consult the book itself, and Aptheker's review may also be read in connection with the Symposium occasioned by Kate Weigand's Red Feminism (S&S, Winter 2002-2003).

D. L.


Back to Prior Page


HOME | INFORMATION FOR SUBSCRIBERS | INSTRUCTIONS FOR CONTRIBUTORS | CURRENT ISSUE CONTENT
BACK CONTENTS | CURRENT EDITORIAL | BACK EDITORIALS | HISTORY AND PROSPECTUS
INDEX | THE EDITORIAL BOARD | EDITORIAL FUNCTIONS | info@scienceandsociety.com
End Point Corporation